imported>Nick Gardner |
imported>Nick Gardner |
(54 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown) |
Line 1: |
Line 1: |
| {{subpages}}
| | ====Germany ==== |
| | :''(with supplementary material from Hans-Joachim Braun (1990) <ref> Hans-Joachim Braun: ''The German Economy in the Twentieth Century'',Routledge 1990 (Questia [http://www.questia.com/read/109044109?title=The%20German%20Economy%20in%20the%20Twentieth%20Century]) </ref>). |
|
| |
|
| :''The data on this page are taken from Bernanke (2000) <ref> Ben Bernanke: ''The Great Depression'', Princeton University Press, 2000</ref>, in addition to the sources indicated. The unemployment rates quoted depend upon then current definitions that varied among countries, and which differ from those now in use.''
| | The severe depression faced by the German economy in the 1930s was partly due to the problems of recovery from the war. War expenditure had been almost completely financed by loans and the money supply had been quadrupled in the period from 1914 to 1918. Inflationary pressures that had started during the war, intensified year by year and culminated in the disastrous [[German hyperinflation]] of 1922-233 <ref>[http://www.usagold.com/germannightmare.html. ''The Nightmare German Inflation'', Scientific Market Analysis, 1970.]</ref>. By the time that prices were stabilised by Hjalmar Schacht's establishment of the "rentenmark" <ref>[http://www.econ.puc-rio.br/gfranco/Ch10.PDF R. Kuczynski "The Rentenmark Miracle and the German stabilization"]</ref>, extensive damage had been done and the banking system had been seriously weakened. In 1923, shortfalls in Germany's payments of reparations had prompted French, Italian and Belgian governments to attempt to seize resources by occupying the Ruhr. The dispute was eventually settled by acceptance of the Dawes Plan <ref>[http://www.u-s-history.com/pages/h1371.html ''The Dawes Plan'' NW travel Magazine online]</ref> of 1924, under which payments would be rescheduled and Germany would be provided with massive loans, mainly from the United States. American financier J. P. Morgan floated the loan on the U.S. market, which was quickly oversubscribed. Over the next four years, U.S. banks continued to lend Germany enough money to enable it to meet its reparation payments to countries such as France and the United Kingdom. These countries, in turn, used their reparation payments from Germany to service their war debts to the United States. |
| | Subsequent recovery had been heavily dependent on imported capital. |
|
| |
|
| ==International Trends==
| | It was in late 1926 that the German authorities decided to restrain the subsequent expansion of economic activity. According to Peter Temin the President of the Reichsbank, Hjalmar Schacht, became worried about stock market speculation and took action that was more severe than that undertaken by the United States' Federal Reserve Bank in 1928, by withdrawing tax exemption from foreign holders of German bonds and forcing banks to reduce discounting. The German stock exchange crashed in 1927, and when the the downturn of economic activity in the United States started in 1929, economic activity in Germany was already declining. |
|
| |
|
| ==Developments in individual countries==
| | In 1930 the wartime allies agreed to the Young Plan <ref>[http://www.bartleby.com/65/yo/YoungPla.html ''The Young Plan'', The Columbia Encyclopedia, 2001-7]</ref>, that rescheduled Germany's reparation payments, but gave priority to the repayment of debts to the United States. Hjalmar Schacht resigned in protest and, in an article in a London magazines, John Maynard Keynes commented that it would " weigh on Germany much more heavily than the Dawes Plan, which it was agreed she could not support"<ref name=Keynes30>[http://www.gutenberg.ca/ebooks/keynes-slump/keynes-slump-00-h.html John Maynard Keynes: ''The Great Slump 1930'', London and Atheneum magazine 1930]</ref>. |
|
| |
|
| ===Europe===
| | In order to stay on the gold standard action was taken in 1930 to stem the outflow of gold and correct a persistent balance of payments deficit. The Reichsbank raised its discount rate to well above British and American rates and there was a sharp reduction in the money supply<ref> There is a detailed account of monetary developments at the time on page 150 of Ben Bernanke: ''Essays on the Great Deflation'', Princeton University Press, 2004 </ref>, and for the next two years (according to Temin (1989) page 31, Chancellor Brüning pursued a relentless policy of highly restrictive budgets. |
|
| |
|
| ====Britain====
| | From April to June 1931, as a result of three years of deflation and the withdrawal of American funds many banks found themselves with insufficient reserves to pay depositors. In June, President Herbert Hoover announced a one year moratorium on international payments-reparations and war debts-and also provided a $150 million credit to the Reichsbank, but withdrawals continued. |
| : ''(with supplementary material from Eichengreen (2002) <ref>[http://www.econ.berkeley.edu/~eichengr/research/floudjohnsonchaptersep16-03.pdf Barry Eichengreen: ''The British Economy Between the Wars'' April 2002]</ref>)''
| |
|
| |
|
| The [[United Kingdom]] economy had been severely damaged by World War 1 by serious human losses, to which were added the losses of many of its overseas markets and many of its overseas assets. Recovery was hampered by a severe post-war depression and - after rejoining the gold standard in 1925 at its pe-war parity with the dollar - by an overvalued currency and a struggle to resist massive gold outflows to the United States. (It was in an attempt to stem those outflows that the Bank of England persuaded the Federal Reserve Bank to engineer a monetary expansion in 1927.) The economy suffered a sharp "slump" (the term used in Britain to denote its share of the great depression) between 1929 and 1931, and the government was then forced by further ouflows, to leave the gold standard - after which the economy showed a steady export-led recovery. There was considerable labour unrest but no banking crisis.
| |
|
| |
|
| In numerical terms, the relevant policy actions and economic trends were as follows.
| | The Reichsbank's discount rate was raised to 15% in July to little effect and there was a run on the German banks and savings banks followed. After a few hours the banks paid out only 20 per cent of the sums demanded by customers; and the government announced a two day bank holiday. A "credit crunch intensified the depression which continued until the Nazi party came to power in 1933 |
|
| |
|
| The Bank of England raised its discount rate in steps from 4.5% in 1928 to a peak of 6% in 1929, reduced it in steps to 2.5% in early 1931, raised it again to 6% in late 1931 and then reduced it to 2% in 1932. There was a budgetary swing from a surplus of 0.4 per cent of GNP in 1929/30 to a deficit
| |
| of 1.3 per cent of GDP in 1932/3. The "General Tariff" of 1932 imposed a 10% tax on all imports except raw materials - with later relaxations for imports from the British Commonwealth.
| |
|
| |
|
| On an index of 1928 = 100, wholesale prices fell to 65 in 1931; and industrial production rose to 117 in 1929, fell to 81 in 1931 and then began to recover. The volume of exports - which had risen by over 50% between 1921 and 1920, fell by over 10% in the early 1930s and recovered to near is 1929 level by 1938. The unemployment rate rose from 10% in 1929 to 22% in 1932 and was back to 10% by 1937.
| | Lausanne Conference <ref>[http://www.associatedcontent.com/article/735145/the_lausanne_conference.html Marquis Cannaby ''The Lausanne Conference'', Associated Content Society, 2008]</ref> |
|
| |
|
| ====France ====
| |
|
| |
|
| :''(with supplementary material from Eichengreen and Wyplosz (89) <ref> Barry Eichengreen and Charles and Wyplosz: ''The Economic Consequences of the Franc Poincaré'', NBER Working Paprt No W2064 1989 </ref> and Mauré <ref> Kenneth Mouré: ''The Gold Standard Illusion. France, the Bank of France and the International Gold Standard, 1914-1939''. Oxford University Press, 2003</ref>)''
| | On an index of 1928 = 100,consumer prices fell to 77 in 1933; and industrial production rose to 110 in 1929, fell to 59 in 1932. Unemployment rose from about 5% in 1929 to 30% in 1932 and did not return to 1929 levels until 1936, and industrial unemployment averaged about 22% compared with France's 10% and The United States' 26% . |
|
| |
|
| [[France]] was the last European country to be affected by the depression. It did not suffer deflation or a downturn in economic activity until 1932, but once its depression got started, it lasted longer than in Britain, and it did not start to recover until 1936 by which time, Britain's recovery was virtually complete. There were major bank failures and runs on several provincial banks in 1930 and 1931, and a riot that brought down the government in 1934 <ref>[http://fh.oxfordjournals.org/cgi/content/abstract/20/3/333 Brian Jenkins: ''The Six Fevrier 1934 and the ‘Survival’ of the French Republic'', Oxford University Press, 2006]</ref>.
| |
|
| |
| France had rejoined the gold standard in 1926, and its central bank had resisted pressures to devalue the Franc until 1936, and it experienced large gold inflows (and according to Bernanke and Mihov <ref> Ben Bernanke and Ilian Mihov: "Deflation and Monetary Contraction in the Great Depression" in Ben Bernanke ''Essays on the Great Depression'', page 141, Princeton University Press 2000</ref> kept to the "rules of the game" and did not sterilise gold inflows, and maintained a monetary policy that was generally contracyclical). Discount rates were maintained in the range 2% to 3.5% throughout the period 1928 - 34 and were raised briefly to 5% in 1935. Fiscal policies were generally expansionary, with a succession of budget deficits.
| |
|
| |
| On an index of 1928 = 100, wholesale prices fell to 48 in 1935; and industrial production rose to 112 in 1929, and remained at that level through 1930, but fell to 71 in 1932 and did not began a recovery until 1935. According to Eichengreen <ref> Barry Eichengreen: ''Lessons from the Great Depression", page 3, The MIT Press 1989 </ref>, French ''Industrial Unemployment'' averaged 10% in the period 1930 to 1938, compared with 15% in the UK and 26% in the US.
| |
|
| |
| ====Germany ====
| |
| rejoined the gold standard in 1924
| |
|
| |
| On an index of 1928 = 100,consumer prices fell to 77 in 1933; and industrial production rose to 110 in 1929, fell to 59 in 1932. Unemployment rose from about 5% in 1929 to 30% in 1932 and did not return to 1929 levels until 1936,
| |
|
| |
| <ref>[http://www.history.ucsb.edu/faculty/marcuse/classes/33d/projects/1920s/Econ20s.htm Daniel Costillo: ''German Economy in the 1920s'' 2003]</ref>
| |
|
| |
|
|
| |
|
Line 42: |
Line 27: |
|
| |
|
|
| |
|
| <ref>[http://www.fcs.edu.uy/multi/phes/Temin.pdf Peter Temin: "Transmission of the Great Depression", | | <ref> Peter Temin: "Transmission of the Great Depression", |
| ''The Journal of Economic Perspectives'', Vol. 7, No. 2. Spring, 1993]</ref> | | ''The Journal of Economic Perspectives'', Vol. 7, No. 2. Spring, 1993 [http://www.fcs.edu.uy/multi/phes/Temin.pdf]</ref> |
| | |
| ====Italy====
| |
| | |
| rejoined the gold standard in 1927 and left it in 1931
| |
| | |
| | |
| The Great Depression hit [[Italy]] very hard. As industries came close to failure they were bought out by the banks in a largely illusionary bail-out - the assets used to fund the purchases were largely worthless. This lead to a financial crisis peaking in 1932 and major government intervention. The Industrial Reconstruction Institute (IRI) was formed in January 1933 and took control of the bank-owned companies, suddenly giving Italy the largest state-owned industrial sector in Europe (excluding the USSR). IRI did rather well with its new responsibilities - restructuring, modernising and rationalising as much as it could. It was a significant factor in post-1945 development. But it took the Italian economy until 1935 to recover the manufacturing levels of 1930 - a position that was only 60% better than that of 1913.
| |
| | |
| ====Spain ====
| |
| [[Spain]] had a relatively isolated economy, with high protective tariffs and was experiencing other economic problems with the need for land reform, overall development, and better education levels. It was not one of the main countries affected by the Depression. However, because the country was destroyed by [[Spanish Civil War|civil war]] and suffered from isolation because of [[Francisco Franco]]'s fascist regime, GDP levels of 1939 were not recovered until 1953.
| |
| | |
| ====Sweden====
| |
| | |
| rejoined the gold standard in 1924 and left it and devalued its currency in 1931
| |
| | |
| On an index of 1928 = 100, wholesale prices fell to 71 in 1931; and and industrial production rose to 129 in 1929, fell to 64 in 1932 and then began to recover
| |
|
| |
| ===Asia===
| |
| | |
| ====Australia ====
| |
| rejoined the gold standard in 1925, left it in 1929 and devalued its currency in 1930
| |
| [[Australia, history|Australia]], with its extreme dependence on exports, particularly primary products such as wool and wheat, is thought to have been one of the hardest-hit countries in the Western world Unemployment reached a record high of 29% in 1932, one of the highest rates in the world. There were also incidents of civil unrest, particularly in Australia's largest city, [[Sydney]].
| |
| | |
| ====Japan====
| |
| rejoined the gold standard in 1930 and left it and devalued its currency in 1931
| |
| [[Japan]], with a growing industrial base, was hurt slightly, with GDP falling 8% 1929-30. The economy recovered by 1932.
| |
| | |
| ====China====
| |
| [[China]] was the only country on the silver standard in an international monetary system dominated by the gold standard. Fluctuations in international silver prices undermined China’s monetary system and destabilized its economy. In response to severe deflation, the state shifted its position toward the market from laissez faire to committed intervention. Establishing a new monetary system, with a different foreign-exchange standard, required deliberate government management; ultimately the process of economic recovery and monetary change politicized the entire Chinese economy.
| |
| | |
| ===The Americas===
| |
| | |
| ====United States====
| |
| {{main|Great Depression in the United States}}
| |
| | |
| rejoined the gold standard in 1919 and left it and devalued its currency in 1933
| |
| | |
| On an index of 1928 = 100, wholesale prices fell to 61 in 1933; and industrial production rose to 115 in 1929, fell to 55 in 1932 and did not return to 1928 levels until 1936
| |
| | |
| The Great Depression had a significant impact on the economy and people of the [[United States]] and began to fully affect the country late in 1930 and early in 1931. The official beginning and ending dates for the economic decline according to the National Beureau of Economic Research were from September of 1929 to March of 1933. At the depth of the downturn, the unemployment rate exceeded 20% and the index of industrial production dropped about 50%. Real or inflation/deflation adjusted gross domestic product ("GDP") grew rapidly after 1933 and surpassed the 1929 high by 1936. There was also a decline or recession from June of 1937 through June of 1938, but real GDP remained above the 1929 high. Employment was much slower to recover. The number of non farm jobs did not surpass the 1929 high until 1939 and the number of total jobs did not surpass the 1929 high until 1941. President [[Herbert Hoover]] was widely blamed, and he was defeated in 1932 by [[Franklin D. Roosevelt]]. Roosevelt launched a [[New Deal]] designed to provide emergency relief to upwards of a third of the population, to recover the economy to normal levels, and to reform failed parts of the economic system. Although F.D.R. reduced unemployment by over 5 million in his first term <ref name=>[http://www.schillerinstitute.org/fid_97-01/002-3_fdr_new_deal.html CRAMER, Hartmut. ''F.D.R.’s 'New Deal': An Example of American System Economics''.<small>This speech opened the third panel of the conference, “On the Subject of Startegic Method, in Bad Schwalbach, Germany on May 28, 2000. Footnotes have been added.</small>]</ref> relatively high unemployment lingered until the early 1940s.
| |
| | |
| ====Canada====
| |
| | |
| rejoined the gold standard in 1926 and left it and devalued its currency in 1931
| |
| | |
| On an index of 1928 = 100, wholesale prices fell to 66 in 1933; and industrial production rose to 119 in 1929, fell to 51 in 1933 and did not return to 1928 levels until 1936
| |
| | |
| [[Canada]] was the country hardest hit by the Great Depression. By 1933 its industrial production had fallen to 51 per cent of its 1928 value, and wholesale prices to 66 per cent. Output did not return to its 1928 level until 1936
| |
| | |
| | |
| ====Latin America====
| |
| Before the 1929 crisis, links between the world economy and [[Latin America]]n economies had been established through American and British investment in Latin American exports to the world. As a result, Latin Americans export industries felt the depression quickly. World prices for commodities such as wheat, coffee and copper plunged. Exports from all of Latin America to the US fell in value from $1.2 billion in 1929 to $335 million in 1933, rising to $660 million in 1940.
| |
| | |
| But on the other hand, the depression led the area governments to develop new local industries and expand consumption and production. Following the example of the New Deal, governments in the area approved regulations and created or improved welfare institutions that helped millions of new industrial workers to achieve a better standard of living.
| |
| | |
| ===South Africa ===
| |
| | |
| The Great Depression had a pronounced economic and political effect on [[South Africa]], as it did to most nations at the time. As world trade slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. Many historians think that the social discomfort caused by the depression was a contributing factor in the defeat of Barry Hertzog and his National Party (South Africa)|National Party in the 1933 general election.
| |
| | |
| | |
| ==References== | | ==References== |
| | | {{reflist}} |
| <references/>
| |
Germany
- (with supplementary material from Hans-Joachim Braun (1990) [1]).
The severe depression faced by the German economy in the 1930s was partly due to the problems of recovery from the war. War expenditure had been almost completely financed by loans and the money supply had been quadrupled in the period from 1914 to 1918. Inflationary pressures that had started during the war, intensified year by year and culminated in the disastrous German hyperinflation of 1922-233 [2]. By the time that prices were stabilised by Hjalmar Schacht's establishment of the "rentenmark" [3], extensive damage had been done and the banking system had been seriously weakened. In 1923, shortfalls in Germany's payments of reparations had prompted French, Italian and Belgian governments to attempt to seize resources by occupying the Ruhr. The dispute was eventually settled by acceptance of the Dawes Plan [4] of 1924, under which payments would be rescheduled and Germany would be provided with massive loans, mainly from the United States. American financier J. P. Morgan floated the loan on the U.S. market, which was quickly oversubscribed. Over the next four years, U.S. banks continued to lend Germany enough money to enable it to meet its reparation payments to countries such as France and the United Kingdom. These countries, in turn, used their reparation payments from Germany to service their war debts to the United States.
Subsequent recovery had been heavily dependent on imported capital.
It was in late 1926 that the German authorities decided to restrain the subsequent expansion of economic activity. According to Peter Temin the President of the Reichsbank, Hjalmar Schacht, became worried about stock market speculation and took action that was more severe than that undertaken by the United States' Federal Reserve Bank in 1928, by withdrawing tax exemption from foreign holders of German bonds and forcing banks to reduce discounting. The German stock exchange crashed in 1927, and when the the downturn of economic activity in the United States started in 1929, economic activity in Germany was already declining.
In 1930 the wartime allies agreed to the Young Plan [5], that rescheduled Germany's reparation payments, but gave priority to the repayment of debts to the United States. Hjalmar Schacht resigned in protest and, in an article in a London magazines, John Maynard Keynes commented that it would " weigh on Germany much more heavily than the Dawes Plan, which it was agreed she could not support"[6].
In order to stay on the gold standard action was taken in 1930 to stem the outflow of gold and correct a persistent balance of payments deficit. The Reichsbank raised its discount rate to well above British and American rates and there was a sharp reduction in the money supply[7], and for the next two years (according to Temin (1989) page 31, Chancellor Brüning pursued a relentless policy of highly restrictive budgets.
From April to June 1931, as a result of three years of deflation and the withdrawal of American funds many banks found themselves with insufficient reserves to pay depositors. In June, President Herbert Hoover announced a one year moratorium on international payments-reparations and war debts-and also provided a $150 million credit to the Reichsbank, but withdrawals continued.
The Reichsbank's discount rate was raised to 15% in July to little effect and there was a run on the German banks and savings banks followed. After a few hours the banks paid out only 20 per cent of the sums demanded by customers; and the government announced a two day bank holiday. A "credit crunch intensified the depression which continued until the Nazi party came to power in 1933
Lausanne Conference [8]
On an index of 1928 = 100,consumer prices fell to 77 in 1933; and industrial production rose to 110 in 1929, fell to 59 in 1932. Unemployment rose from about 5% in 1929 to 30% in 1932 and did not return to 1929 levels until 1936, and industrial unemployment averaged about 22% compared with France's 10% and The United States' 26% .
[9]
[10]
References
- ↑ Hans-Joachim Braun: The German Economy in the Twentieth Century,Routledge 1990 (Questia [1])
- ↑ The Nightmare German Inflation, Scientific Market Analysis, 1970.
- ↑ R. Kuczynski "The Rentenmark Miracle and the German stabilization"
- ↑ The Dawes Plan NW travel Magazine online
- ↑ The Young Plan, The Columbia Encyclopedia, 2001-7
- ↑ John Maynard Keynes: The Great Slump 1930, London and Atheneum magazine 1930
- ↑ There is a detailed account of monetary developments at the time on page 150 of Ben Bernanke: Essays on the Great Deflation, Princeton University Press, 2004
- ↑ Marquis Cannaby The Lausanne Conference, Associated Content Society, 2008
- ↑ Mäuge Adalet: Fundamentals, Capital Flows and Capital Flight: The German Banking Crisis of 1931 2005
- ↑ Peter Temin: "Transmission of the Great Depression",
The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 7, No. 2. Spring, 1993 [2]