Great Depression: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
mNo edit summary
 
(79 intermediate revisions by 4 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{subpages}}
{{subpages}}
{|align="center" cellpadding="5" style="background:lightgray; width:95%; border: 1px solid #aaa; margin:20px; font-size: 92%;"
| Supplements to this article include an [[/Timelines|'''annotated chronology of the main events in the countries affected''']]  ; a  [[/Tutorials|'''discussion of economic theories concerning causes and remedies''']]; and  more detailed [[Great Depression in the United States|'''accounts of developments in the United States''']], '''[[Great Depression in Germany|Germany]]''', '''[[Great Depression in the United Kingdom|the United Kingdom]]''' and '''[[Showa Depression (Japan)|Japan]]'''.
|}
The '''Great Depression''' was the longest and deepest downturn in economic activity in modern history. It has had a profound influence upon economic theory, the practice of economic management, and social policy.


The '''Great Depression'''  <ref>The editors of the British journal ''The Economist'' have suggested that the term depression is conventionally applied to a decline in real GDP that exceeds 10%, or one that lasts more than three years. [http://www.economist.com/finance/economicsfocus/displaystory.cfm?story_id=12852043]But ''The Economist'' also notes that prior to the Great Depression any economic "recession" was called a "depression." The term "recession" was a fairly-recent invention designed "to avoid stirring up nasty memories." </ref> was the longest and deepest downturn in economic activity in modern history. It was the unintended consequence of practices that were unquestioned at the time of its outset, and it has since prompted a critical examination of those practices that has had a profound influence upon both economic theory  and the practice of economic management.
Following the [[Crash of 1929]], the United States experienced a deep decline in prices and productionBusinesses and banks closed, people lost their jobs, homes, and savings; and in the absence of welfare programs, many depended on charity to surviveAt its worst, in 1933, U.S. unemployment reached a poverty-inducing 25 per cent of the working population, and in the ensuing recovery, it did not fall below 15 per cent until the beginning of the [[Second World War]].  


In 1929, the United States experienced a  deep decline in prices and production. Businesses and banks closed, people lost their jobs, homes, and savings; and in the absence of welfare programmes, many depended on charity to survive. At its worst, in 1933, unemployment reached a poverty-inducing  25 per cent of the working population: and in the ensuing recovery, it did not fall below 15 per cent until the beginning of the second world war.  
At about the same time, the German and Canadian economies suffered downturns of comparable severity.  The British economy experienced a substantial though comparatively short-lived downturn. The French economy suffered a modest but prolonged decline. In Japan, the downturn was also modest but shorterMost other industrialized countries and their suppliers experienced downturns in economic activity that caused hardship and political unrest.


At about the same time, the German and Canadian economies suffered  downturns of comparable severity; the British economy experienced a substantial though comparatively short-lived downturn; the French economy suffered a modest but prolonged decline; and most of the other industrialised countries and their suppliers  experienced substantial downturns in economic activity that caused hardship and political unrest.
Subsequent investigations have attempted to discover the causes for the length and severity of the depression, its global scope, and the effectiveness of various governmental policies. The answers to those problems remain incomplete but there is a limited consensus among economists  concerning its principal features and concerning the appropriate policy response to a threat of a comparable downturn.


Subsequent investigations have attempted to discover why the downturn in economic activity  had been so deep and so prolonged,  why there it had happened in so many different countries, and what policy actions might have been effective in combatting  it. The answers to those questions remain controversial but a limited consensus has emerged concerning the appropriate policy response to a threat of a comparable downturn. 
==Supplementary material==
 
The following supplementary material is available:
'''Note on numerical sources'''
* an annotated [[/Timelines|chronology]] of the main events in the countries affected;
:''The ability to make reliable quantitative statements about events in the 1930s is limited by the availability and accuracy  of the [[economic statistics]] of that time. By the late 1930s the League of  Nations was publishing a limited range of statistics of unemployment and production collated from national sources, but many countries had not yet to begun  publication of national statistics.''
* a discussion of economic theories concerning [[/Tutorials| causes and remedies]]; and
 
* more detailed accounts of developments  [[Great Depression in the United States|the United States]], [[Great Depression in Germany|Germany]], [[Great Depression in the United Kingdom|the United Kingdom]], and [[Showa Depression (Japan)|Japan]].
'''Links and subpages'''
:''For an annotated chronology of the main events in the countries affected, see the [[/Timelines|Timelines subpage]];''
 
:'' for more about events within the United States, see the article on the [[Great Depression in the United States]];''
 
:''for more about the events in countries outside the United States, see the [[/Addendum|Addendum subpage]]; and,''
 
:'' for a discussion of economic theories concerning  causes and remedies, see the  [[/Tutorials |Tutorials subpage]].)''


==Overview==
==Overview==
The great depression, which is generally considered to have started in the United States in 1929, reached its zenith there in 1933 and lasted until 1939.  Severe downturns in economic activity also occurred during that period in most of the other industrialised countries and among their suppliers of raw materials; and there was a major reduction in the volume of international trade.
In the United States, the Great Depression <ref>The editors of the British journal ''The Economist'' have suggested that the term depression is conventionally applied to a decline in real GDP that exceeds 10%, or one that lasts more than three years. [http://www.economist.com/finance/economicsfocus/displaystory.cfm?story_id=12852043].  But ''The Economist'' also notes that prior to the Great Depression any economic [[recession]] was called a "depression."  Economists since 1929 have used the term "recession" "to avoid stirring up nasty memories." </ref> began in 1929, reached its deepest point in 1933 and lasted until 1939.  It was accompanied during that period by a stock change crash, a series of banking crises, a [[credit crunch]], and a severe [[deflation]].  It resulted in a massive loss of output, persistently high [[Employment|unemployment]] and widespread deprivation. A similar sequence of events occurred at about the same time in Germany, downturns of differing severity also occurred in many industrialized and commodity-producing currencies, and there was a general collapse in international trade. Some years after its outset there was a general return to previous levels of economic activity, but the  economies of the United States and of several other countries did not fully recover until the outbreak of the [[Second World War]].
 
   
In the United States, it was accompanied during that period by the stock exchange [[crash of 1929]], the [[banking crisis of 1931]], a credit crunch,  and a severe [[deflation]]; and it resulted in a massive loss of output, persistently high [[unemployment]] and widespread deprivation. There were depressions of comparable severity in the industrialised economies of Canada and Germany, and of lesser magnitude  in Britain, France  and Scandinavia. There were major price reductions  reductions in the international commodity markets, and  severe downturns in the  commodity-producing economies of Australia and  South America. The resulting hardships had significant repercussions upon the conduct of politics, including the replacement of existing national governments - notably in Germany - and a deterioration of international relations, reflected in the development of trade wars. 
The resulting hardships had significant political repercussions, including the replacement of existing national governments&mdash;notably in Germany&mdash;and a deterioration of international relations, but besides causing widespread human suffering, the great depression stimulated major investigations into  its causes; gave birth to [[macroeconomics]] as a distinct field of study, and the genesis of the rival theories [[Keynesianism]] and [[Monetarism]]; and led to the systematic collection and publication of [[economic statistics]]. It has exerted a major influence upon political beliefs and ideologies and despite continuing  controversy,  it has  generated  major changes in the  consensus views of economists and politicians. It  has also led to international agreements on economic issues, such as that reached at the [[Bretton Woods Conference]], and to  the creation of instruments of international cooperation such as the [[Bank for International Settlements]], the [[International Monetary Fund]], the [[World Bank]] and the [[World Trade Organisation]].
 
Besides causing widespread human suffering, the great depression stimulated major investigations of its causes and gave birth to [[macroeconomics]] as a distinct field of study, and the genesis of the rival theories [[Keynesianism]] and [[Monetarism]]; and led to the systematic collection and publication of [[economic statistics]]. It has exerted a major influence upon economists' beliefs and policy recommendations and political ideologies; and despite continuing  controversy,  it has  generated  major changes in the  consensus views of those matters  among economists and politicians, It  has also led to international agreements on economic issues, such as the [[Bretton Woods Conference]], and to  the creation of instruments of international cooperation such as the [[Bank for International Settlements]], the [[International Monetary Fund]], the [[World Bank]] and the [[World Trade Organisation]].


==The development of the depression==
==The development of the depression==
A central cause of the Great Depression were the economic consequences of the [[Treaty of Versailles]]. The post-World-War-One recovery required a long and difficult period of adaptation for its European participants. After a turbulent post-war period during which there were deep but short-lived [[recession]]s on both sides of the Atlantic, there was renewed economic growth in the United States and Europe. The UK and France had incurred huge wartime debts to the United States and Germany was faced with crippling reparations payments. Suspension of war debt repayment was dismissed by the U.S. and the UK and France had few other easy alternatives than squeezing Germany for reparations.  When Germany attempted to meet the reparations schedule, beginning in 1922, it's economy collapsed within months and was in technical payment default by January 1923.  This collapse precipitated the Ruhr Crisis, a general strike in Germany, and hyperinflation.  The U.S. attempted to stabilize the European flow of capital through the [[Dawes Plan]] by which the U.S. essentially bailed out the German economy.  With the U.S. and European economies now closely tied together, however, the Dawes Plan (and its modification, the [[Young Plan]]) guaranteed that any downturn in the U.S. economy would be quickly exported to Europe.<ref>[http://www.history.ucsb.edu/faculty/marcuse/classes/33d/projects/1920s/Econ20s.htm Daniel Costillo: ''German Economy in the 1920s'' 2003].  Editor's note: Costillo may have made the argument that Germany was attempting to reflate its economy in 1922 which precipitated the German hyperinflation.  Someone needs to verify the applicability of Costillo as a source for this paragraph.</ref>


:''(The chronological list of the events referred to in this paragraph that appears  on the [[/Timelines|Timelines subpage]], also provides links to the sources of the statements that it contains)''
The return to the [[gold standard]] in the following decade, after its wartime suspension, had involved further disruption. The United Kingdom rejoined the [[gold standard]] in 1925 at an [[exchange rate]] that overvalued the pound, and France rejoined it in 1928 at an exchange rate that undervalued the franc. There followed a series of British trade deficits and gold outflows and a series of French trade surpluses and gold inflows. By 1927, the [[Bank of England]]'s gold reserves were running so low that its governor persuaded the [[Federal Reserve System|Federal Reserve Bank of New York]] to lower its [[discount rate]].  
 
Although it ended eleven years  earlier, there are reasons to suppose that the [[First World War]] played a part in the development of the great depression. Professor Peter Temin of the Massachussets Institute of Technology argues that the war had been the shock that had set the process in motion, by producing  disruptive changes to  the economic systems that required a difficult period of adaptation <ref name=TeminL> Peter Temin: ''Lessons from the Great Depression'', MIT Press 1989]</ref>. He argues that the pattern of international capital movements, in particular, had been disrupted by the fact that when the war ended, the American economy was much stronger and European economies were much weaker; and by the fact that Britain and France had to repay the debts to America that they had incurred during the war.


After a turbulent post-war period  during which there were deep but short-lived recessions on both sides of the Atlantic, economic growth had returned to the United States and Europe, except that in Germany, attempts to reflate the economy had led to its interruption by the [[German hyperinflation]] of 1923 <ref>[http://www.history.ucsb.edu/faculty/marcuse/classes/33d/projects/1920s/Econ20s.htm Daniel Costillo: ''German Economy in the 1920s'' 2003]</ref>. After the restoration of price stability, German economic growth resumed in 1924 with the assistance of Dawes Plan loans from the United States.
The downturns in activity that led to the Great Depression began at the end of the 1920s following restrictionary policies in the United States and in Germany prompted by the wish to restrain stock exchange speculation and by concern about gold outflows.  Both downturns were comparatively mild at first, but they became exceptionally severe  in both countries following  the stock exchange [[crash of 1929]] and the [[US banking crises of 1931-33]]. There were depressions of somewhat smaller magnitude in the UK, France and Scandinavia, and the major price reductions that occurred in the international commodity markets led to severe downturns in the commodity-producing economies of Australia and South America.


By 1927, the Bank of England was in serious financial difficulties after having rejoined the [[gold standard]] at an unfavoruable exchange rate, and its Governor persuaded the Governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to help by organising a major addition to the United States money supply. There followed a sharp increase in America's output growth rate (prompting  John Maynard Keynes to remark that "...the world was enormously enriched by the constructions of the quinquennium from 1925 to 1929; its wealth increased in these five years by as much as in any other ten or twenty years of its history" <ref name=Keynes3> John Maynard Keynes: "An Economic Analysis of Unemployment", in ''The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes'', Macmillan 1973 </ref>.) and an even sharper increase in the the growth of prices on the New York Stock Exchange.
In the United States, the recovery began in 1933 after the election of a new administration under the Presidency of [[Franklin D. Roosevelt]] and the launching of the [[New Deal]]. In 1993, the President suspended the gold standard, imposed  a brief banking "holiday", sponsored the insurance of bank deposits, and  provided the banks with substantial  financial assistance. The [[Federal Reserve system]] began to expand the [[monetary base]], and there followed a limited and delayed increase in the [[money supply]] <ref name=stats>See the statistics on the tutorials page of the article on the Great Depression in the United States [http://en.citizendium.org/wiki/Great_Depression_in_the_United_States/Tutorials]</ref>. Confidence in the banking system returned, but the credit shortage was only very gradually relieved, and small firms continued to experience  credit difficulties for several years after 1933. The New Deal also involved a modest fiscal stimulus <ref> The [[fiscal stimulus]] is described as modest, because it only amounted to about 3 per cent of gdp [http://en.citizendium.org/wiki/Great_Depression_in_the_United_States/Tutorials] in face of a 40 per cent downturn in activity.</ref> and introduced a  programme of public works known as the  [[New Deal]]. There was a slow recovery in output, interrupted by a brief downturn in the [[Recession of 1937]], but it although GDP had returned to its long-term trend by the end of 1938 unemployment continued for some time at an above-trend level .


According to Peter Temin<ref name=TeminT>[http://www.fcs.edu.uy/multi/phes/Temin.pdf, Peter Temin: "Transmission of the Great Depression", ''Journal of Economic Perspectives'', Spring 1993]</ref> the downturn that became the Great Depression began at the end of the 1920s with restrictionary policies in the United States and Germany (said to have been prompted both by a wish to restrain stock exchange speculation and by a determination to comply with the rules of the [[gold standard]]). Downturns in both countries during 1929 were comparatively mild, but they became exceptionally severe in the years following the New York Stock Exchange [[crash of 1929]]. Their severity was increased by banking crises and consequent credit shortages, and recovery did not begin until 1933.
In Germany, the Nazi government under the Chancellorship of [[Adolf Hitler]] repudiated all international obligations and adopted a varied programme of reflation and rearmament, which was immediately effective in reducing unemployment and restoring economic growth.


Recovery from the recession began in 1931 in Britain, Scandinavia and Japan following their suspesion of the gold standard, but not until 1933 in America and Germany, nor until 1935 in France. In the United States a new administration under the Presidency of [[Franklin D. Roosevelt]] undertook an extensive programme of public works known as the [[New Deal]], and in Germany the Nazi government under the Chancellorship of [[Adolf Hitler]] repudiated all international obligations and adopted a varied programme of reflation and rearmament.
Recovery from the recession began in 1931 in the UK, Scandinavia and Japan <ref> Summaries of the recoveries of countries other than the United States are available on the Addendum subpage</ref>  following currency devaluations made possible by departures from the [[gold standard]].  Recovery did not begin in France until its departure from the gold standard in 1936.


==Explanations==
==Explanations==
===The question of causation===
===The question of causation===
There have been a great number of attempts to establish the cause of  what has come to be seen as an unprecedented self-inflicted injury, and a great deal of disagreement. However, the unprecedented feature of the great depression was not its initiation (there had been a succession of recessions in the United States throughout the previous eighty years <ref>[http://www.nber.org/cycles/ ''US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions'' NBER 2008]</ref>, and it was no worse in its early months than the preceding recession of 1921 <ref>[http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_hb5814/is_n3_v29/ai_n28604039  J R Vernon: ''The 1920-21 Deflation'', Economic Inquiry,  July, 1991]</ref>) - but, rather, its unprecedented severity and persistent depth.  That consideration  and others suggest that any  search for a single cause is likely to be confusing and inconclusive. For example, although the popular view  that it was initiated by the stock market crash can be shown to be mistaken <ref> Because the economic downturn started before the crash - see the paragraph on the crash on the [[/Tutorials|tutorials subpage]]</ref>, it must be presumed to have contributed to its subsequent severity. Similarly, it can reasonably  be presumed that although the 1931 banking panic could not have started the great depression, it intensified its subsequent severity.
There have been many attempts to establish the cause of the depression and to explain its unprecedented depth and duration - but no definitive explanation has emerged. Because of the complexity of the interactions among the factors that were involved it now seems that any  search for a single cause is likely to be confusing and inconclusive. For example, although the popular view  that it was initiated by the stock market crash can be shown to be mistaken <ref> Because the economic downturn started before the crash - see the paragraph on the crash on the [[/Tutorials|tutorials subpage]]</ref>, the crash must be presumed to have contributed to its subsequent severity. Similarly, it can reasonably  be presumed that although the 1931 banking panic could not have started the great depression, there is no doubt that it intensified its subsequent severity. In what follows, designation "contributory factor" rather than a "cause" is not intended to suggest that the factor in question  is of lesser importance.
 
===Rival Theories===
 
===Contributory factors===
 
''(the discussion in the following paragraphs is based upon material that is set out in more detail on the tutorials subpage)''
 
 
U.S. imports from Europe declined from a 1929 high of $1,334 million to just $390 million in 1932, while U.S. exports to Europe fell from $2,341 million in 1929 to $784 million in 1932. Overall, world trade declined by some 66% between 1929 and 1934.
<ref>[http://future.state.gov/when/timeline/1921_timeline/smoot_tariff.html Smoot-Hawley Tariff US state Department]</ref>


===Rival Hypotheses===
Among rival explanations is the belief that the Great Depression was started by the bursting of a speculative [[Asset price bubble|bubble]] on the New York stock exchange and that it spread abroad from the United States, causing the collapse  of a hitherto well-functioning system of international finance. Those beliefs have been challenged by the eminent economists who have studied the evidence. According to Ben Bernanke there is a consensus that the picture of a stock exchange [[bubble (economics)|bubble]] that had been verbally painted by John Kenneth Galbraith and others is mistaken, and that the stock prices did not at that time overstate the value of the issuing companies <ref> For the evidence supporting the contention that stocks were not overvalued, see the article on the [[Crash of 1929]]</ref>. Moreover, neither [[/Tutorials#Keynes and the Keynesians|John Maynard Keynes]]  nor [[/Tutorials#Milton Friedman and the Chicago School|Milton Friedman]] considered the stock exchange crash to have started the downturn, although they both  recognised that it must have contributed to its severity. The belief that the depression originated uniquely in the United States has been challenged by [[/Tutorials#Peter Temin|Peter Temin]], who has identified evidence that it had an independent origin in Germany, and has suggested that it developed jointly from both origins. The belief that the depression put an end to what had been a stable international financial system has been challenged by [[/Tutorials#Charles Kindleberger|Charles Kindleberger]], who argues that, although the [[gold standard]] system had worked well before the first world war, its post-war version had a bias toward deflation that made it inherently unstable. Peter Temin has argued that the belief that the depression had been intensified by economic nationalism should be qualified by the consideration that the "trade war" could not have had much effect upon the United States because international trade had occupied too small a part in its economy; and the belief that trading had been hampered by the competitive devaluation of national currencies has been challenged by [[/Tutorials#Barry Eichengreen|Barry Eichengreen]] on the basis of evidence that it had contributed to world output.


The belief that policy mistakes had contributed to the disaster is generally accepted by economists, but there is disagreement among them concerning the nature of those mistakes, and concerning the economists' beliefs upon which they had been founded. The belief that had been current at the time that  economic  instability results from government attempts at regulation and that  action to counter  recessions makes them worse, is not widely accepted nowadays, except by some economists of the [[Austrian School]], and there are few who now believe that maintenance of  a balanced budget and adherence to the gold standard are essential for the maintenance  of price stability. The principle remaining controversy concerns the roles of fiscal and monetary policy. In their time, [[/Tutorials#Friedrich Hayek|Friedrich Hayek]] had laid the entire blame for the depression upon the Federal Reserve's 1924 monetary expansion, whereas  John Maynard Keynes and Milton Friedman had held its 1928 monetary contraction to have been largely responsible. Milton Friedman blamed the Federal Reserve for continuing to restrict the money supply after the depression had started, whereas John Maynard Keynes had warned President Roosevelt against reliance upon expanding the money supply and voiced concern about what he considered to be the President's reluctance to introduce an adequate  fiscal expansion.


==Consequences==
==Consequences==
Among the observable consequences of the Great Depression were personal losses of jobs, savings and homes, and there were reports that in Germany and the United States, in particular, that was accompanied by hunger, ill-health, and even starvation. It must also have had  effects upon social attitudes that were not observable, except indirectly in the form of occasional riots and hunger marches. It would be rash to attribute the political upheavals of the 1930s exclusively to the widespread personal hardships that were being suffered at the time, but an association between those developments was certainly evident. Political organisations that offered relief by means of increased social intervention in the conduct of industry and commerce gained power at the expense of the  mainly laissez-faire governments of the 1920s. In Germany, Italy and Japan the gains went to totalitarians, in France to social democrats,  and in the United States to Roosevelt's [[New Deal]] Democrats. The chief exception was the UK, where the social democrat Labour Party was displaced by a conventionally conservative coalition.


<ref>[http://www.baas.ac.uk/resources/pamphlets/pamphdets.asp?id=7 James. Patterson, The Welfare State in America, 1930-1980 BAAS Pamphlet No. 7 British Association for American Studies 1981]</ref>
In contrast to the reported tendency toward increased social cohesion of the 1930s <ref>[http://www.enotes.com/1930-lifestyles-social-trends-american-decades/red-decade-solidarity-individualism Matthew Bruccoli and Richard Layman (eds): ''1930's Lifestyles and Social Trends: The Red Decade: Solidarity and Individualism in the 1930s.'', eNotes.com. 2006] </ref>  
 
within countries, it was a period of strained relations and intensified rivalry  between countries.
 
 
==Remedies==
===Rescue===
===Reform===
 


==References==
==References==
<references />
{{reflist}}[[Category:Suggestion Bot Tag]]

Latest revision as of 16:00, 23 August 2024

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Timelines [?]
Tutorials [?]
Addendum [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.
Supplements to this article include an annotated chronology of the main events in the countries affected  ; a discussion of economic theories concerning causes and remedies; and more detailed accounts of developments in the United States, Germany, the United Kingdom and Japan.

The Great Depression was the longest and deepest downturn in economic activity in modern history. It has had a profound influence upon economic theory, the practice of economic management, and social policy.

Following the Crash of 1929, the United States experienced a deep decline in prices and production. Businesses and banks closed, people lost their jobs, homes, and savings; and in the absence of welfare programs, many depended on charity to survive. At its worst, in 1933, U.S. unemployment reached a poverty-inducing 25 per cent of the working population, and in the ensuing recovery, it did not fall below 15 per cent until the beginning of the Second World War.

At about the same time, the German and Canadian economies suffered downturns of comparable severity. The British economy experienced a substantial though comparatively short-lived downturn. The French economy suffered a modest but prolonged decline. In Japan, the downturn was also modest but shorter. Most other industrialized countries and their suppliers experienced downturns in economic activity that caused hardship and political unrest.

Subsequent investigations have attempted to discover the causes for the length and severity of the depression, its global scope, and the effectiveness of various governmental policies. The answers to those problems remain incomplete but there is a limited consensus among economists concerning its principal features and concerning the appropriate policy response to a threat of a comparable downturn.

Supplementary material

The following supplementary material is available:

Overview

In the United States, the Great Depression [1] began in 1929, reached its deepest point in 1933 and lasted until 1939. It was accompanied during that period by a stock change crash, a series of banking crises, a credit crunch, and a severe deflation. It resulted in a massive loss of output, persistently high unemployment and widespread deprivation. A similar sequence of events occurred at about the same time in Germany, downturns of differing severity also occurred in many industrialized and commodity-producing currencies, and there was a general collapse in international trade. Some years after its outset there was a general return to previous levels of economic activity, but the economies of the United States and of several other countries did not fully recover until the outbreak of the Second World War.

The resulting hardships had significant political repercussions, including the replacement of existing national governments—notably in Germany—and a deterioration of international relations, but besides causing widespread human suffering, the great depression stimulated major investigations into its causes; gave birth to macroeconomics as a distinct field of study, and the genesis of the rival theories Keynesianism and Monetarism; and led to the systematic collection and publication of economic statistics. It has exerted a major influence upon political beliefs and ideologies and despite continuing controversy, it has generated major changes in the consensus views of economists and politicians. It has also led to international agreements on economic issues, such as that reached at the Bretton Woods Conference, and to the creation of instruments of international cooperation such as the Bank for International Settlements, the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank and the World Trade Organisation.

The development of the depression

A central cause of the Great Depression were the economic consequences of the Treaty of Versailles. The post-World-War-One recovery required a long and difficult period of adaptation for its European participants. After a turbulent post-war period during which there were deep but short-lived recessions on both sides of the Atlantic, there was renewed economic growth in the United States and Europe. The UK and France had incurred huge wartime debts to the United States and Germany was faced with crippling reparations payments. Suspension of war debt repayment was dismissed by the U.S. and the UK and France had few other easy alternatives than squeezing Germany for reparations. When Germany attempted to meet the reparations schedule, beginning in 1922, it's economy collapsed within months and was in technical payment default by January 1923. This collapse precipitated the Ruhr Crisis, a general strike in Germany, and hyperinflation. The U.S. attempted to stabilize the European flow of capital through the Dawes Plan by which the U.S. essentially bailed out the German economy. With the U.S. and European economies now closely tied together, however, the Dawes Plan (and its modification, the Young Plan) guaranteed that any downturn in the U.S. economy would be quickly exported to Europe.[2]

The return to the gold standard in the following decade, after its wartime suspension, had involved further disruption. The United Kingdom rejoined the gold standard in 1925 at an exchange rate that overvalued the pound, and France rejoined it in 1928 at an exchange rate that undervalued the franc. There followed a series of British trade deficits and gold outflows and a series of French trade surpluses and gold inflows. By 1927, the Bank of England's gold reserves were running so low that its governor persuaded the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to lower its discount rate.

The downturns in activity that led to the Great Depression began at the end of the 1920s following restrictionary policies in the United States and in Germany prompted by the wish to restrain stock exchange speculation and by concern about gold outflows. Both downturns were comparatively mild at first, but they became exceptionally severe in both countries following the stock exchange crash of 1929 and the US banking crises of 1931-33. There were depressions of somewhat smaller magnitude in the UK, France and Scandinavia, and the major price reductions that occurred in the international commodity markets led to severe downturns in the commodity-producing economies of Australia and South America.

In the United States, the recovery began in 1933 after the election of a new administration under the Presidency of Franklin D. Roosevelt and the launching of the New Deal. In 1993, the President suspended the gold standard, imposed a brief banking "holiday", sponsored the insurance of bank deposits, and provided the banks with substantial financial assistance. The Federal Reserve system began to expand the monetary base, and there followed a limited and delayed increase in the money supply [3]. Confidence in the banking system returned, but the credit shortage was only very gradually relieved, and small firms continued to experience credit difficulties for several years after 1933. The New Deal also involved a modest fiscal stimulus [4] and introduced a programme of public works known as the New Deal. There was a slow recovery in output, interrupted by a brief downturn in the Recession of 1937, but it although GDP had returned to its long-term trend by the end of 1938 unemployment continued for some time at an above-trend level .

In Germany, the Nazi government under the Chancellorship of Adolf Hitler repudiated all international obligations and adopted a varied programme of reflation and rearmament, which was immediately effective in reducing unemployment and restoring economic growth.

Recovery from the recession began in 1931 in the UK, Scandinavia and Japan [5] following currency devaluations made possible by departures from the gold standard. Recovery did not begin in France until its departure from the gold standard in 1936.

Explanations

The question of causation

There have been many attempts to establish the cause of the depression and to explain its unprecedented depth and duration - but no definitive explanation has emerged. Because of the complexity of the interactions among the factors that were involved it now seems that any search for a single cause is likely to be confusing and inconclusive. For example, although the popular view that it was initiated by the stock market crash can be shown to be mistaken [6], the crash must be presumed to have contributed to its subsequent severity. Similarly, it can reasonably be presumed that although the 1931 banking panic could not have started the great depression, there is no doubt that it intensified its subsequent severity. In what follows, designation "contributory factor" rather than a "cause" is not intended to suggest that the factor in question is of lesser importance.

Rival Hypotheses

Among rival explanations is the belief that the Great Depression was started by the bursting of a speculative bubble on the New York stock exchange and that it spread abroad from the United States, causing the collapse of a hitherto well-functioning system of international finance. Those beliefs have been challenged by the eminent economists who have studied the evidence. According to Ben Bernanke there is a consensus that the picture of a stock exchange bubble that had been verbally painted by John Kenneth Galbraith and others is mistaken, and that the stock prices did not at that time overstate the value of the issuing companies [7]. Moreover, neither John Maynard Keynes nor Milton Friedman considered the stock exchange crash to have started the downturn, although they both recognised that it must have contributed to its severity. The belief that the depression originated uniquely in the United States has been challenged by Peter Temin, who has identified evidence that it had an independent origin in Germany, and has suggested that it developed jointly from both origins. The belief that the depression put an end to what had been a stable international financial system has been challenged by Charles Kindleberger, who argues that, although the gold standard system had worked well before the first world war, its post-war version had a bias toward deflation that made it inherently unstable. Peter Temin has argued that the belief that the depression had been intensified by economic nationalism should be qualified by the consideration that the "trade war" could not have had much effect upon the United States because international trade had occupied too small a part in its economy; and the belief that trading had been hampered by the competitive devaluation of national currencies has been challenged by Barry Eichengreen on the basis of evidence that it had contributed to world output.

The belief that policy mistakes had contributed to the disaster is generally accepted by economists, but there is disagreement among them concerning the nature of those mistakes, and concerning the economists' beliefs upon which they had been founded. The belief that had been current at the time that economic instability results from government attempts at regulation and that action to counter recessions makes them worse, is not widely accepted nowadays, except by some economists of the Austrian School, and there are few who now believe that maintenance of a balanced budget and adherence to the gold standard are essential for the maintenance of price stability. The principle remaining controversy concerns the roles of fiscal and monetary policy. In their time, Friedrich Hayek had laid the entire blame for the depression upon the Federal Reserve's 1924 monetary expansion, whereas John Maynard Keynes and Milton Friedman had held its 1928 monetary contraction to have been largely responsible. Milton Friedman blamed the Federal Reserve for continuing to restrict the money supply after the depression had started, whereas John Maynard Keynes had warned President Roosevelt against reliance upon expanding the money supply and voiced concern about what he considered to be the President's reluctance to introduce an adequate fiscal expansion.

Consequences

Among the observable consequences of the Great Depression were personal losses of jobs, savings and homes, and there were reports that in Germany and the United States, in particular, that was accompanied by hunger, ill-health, and even starvation. It must also have had effects upon social attitudes that were not observable, except indirectly in the form of occasional riots and hunger marches. It would be rash to attribute the political upheavals of the 1930s exclusively to the widespread personal hardships that were being suffered at the time, but an association between those developments was certainly evident. Political organisations that offered relief by means of increased social intervention in the conduct of industry and commerce gained power at the expense of the mainly laissez-faire governments of the 1920s. In Germany, Italy and Japan the gains went to totalitarians, in France to social democrats, and in the United States to Roosevelt's New Deal Democrats. The chief exception was the UK, where the social democrat Labour Party was displaced by a conventionally conservative coalition.

In contrast to the reported tendency toward increased social cohesion of the 1930s [8] within countries, it was a period of strained relations and intensified rivalry between countries.

References

  1. The editors of the British journal The Economist have suggested that the term depression is conventionally applied to a decline in real GDP that exceeds 10%, or one that lasts more than three years. [1]. But The Economist also notes that prior to the Great Depression any economic recession was called a "depression." Economists since 1929 have used the term "recession" "to avoid stirring up nasty memories."
  2. Daniel Costillo: German Economy in the 1920s 2003. Editor's note: Costillo may have made the argument that Germany was attempting to reflate its economy in 1922 which precipitated the German hyperinflation. Someone needs to verify the applicability of Costillo as a source for this paragraph.
  3. See the statistics on the tutorials page of the article on the Great Depression in the United States [2]
  4. The fiscal stimulus is described as modest, because it only amounted to about 3 per cent of gdp [3] in face of a 40 per cent downturn in activity.
  5. Summaries of the recoveries of countries other than the United States are available on the Addendum subpage
  6. Because the economic downturn started before the crash - see the paragraph on the crash on the tutorials subpage
  7. For the evidence supporting the contention that stocks were not overvalued, see the article on the Crash of 1929
  8. Matthew Bruccoli and Richard Layman (eds): 1930's Lifestyles and Social Trends: The Red Decade: Solidarity and Individualism in the 1930s., eNotes.com. 2006