Cost-benefit analysis: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Howard C. Berkowitz
(Quality- and disability-adjusted years of life saved)
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 7: Line 7:


==Specification==
==Specification==
===Criteria===
The customary ("[[consequentialism|consequentialist]]") decision criterion of  cost-benefit analysis uses the summation of the effects  of the expected consequences of a decision on the well-being of people within its scope.  The alternative ("[[deontology|deontologist]]") decision criterion takes account of the views of those affected concerning the need to conform to predetermined rules (such as the sacredness of human life or the prohibition of interest-paying debt). To make a summation possible, a monetary cost or benefit is assigned to each of those effects. (Monetisation under the deontology criterion may be based upon the costs of socially-agreed practices that conform to the relevant rules)  The summation normally used is then that of the costs and benefits of  each effect, weighted by their estimated probability of occurrence, and discounted using the estimated time preference rates of those affected. The normal acceptance criterion for a single project is a positive  net present expected value of the excess of benefits over costs, and the normal  criterion for the acceptance of one among several alternatives  is that it should be the one with the  highest net present expected value.
===Scope===
===Scope===
The scope of an analysis is normally determined by the requirements of its prospective users. The evaluation of a medical procedure might, for example, be concerned solely with its effects on patients and their families, or it might also encompass  effects on the  hospital or on the public at large. An evaluation of migration commissioned by a European government might or might not be required to include effects upon migrants and their families, but an evaluation commissioned by the European Union might be expected to require the inclusion of effects upon all of its inhabitants. Some users require the  coverage of a longer timescale than others,  and environmental studies may even be required to encompass effects on future generations.
The scope of an analysis is normally determined by the requirements of its prospective users. The evaluation of a medical procedure might, for example, be concerned solely with its effects on patients and their families, or it might also encompass  effects on the  hospital or on the public at large. An evaluation of migration commissioned by a European government might or might not be required to include effects upon migrants and their families, but an evaluation commissioned by the European Union might be expected to require the inclusion of effects upon all of its inhabitants. Some users require the  coverage of a longer timescale than others,  and environmental studies may even be required to encompass effects on future generations.


Reports that do not specify the scope of a quoted cost-benefit analysis are open to misinterpretation.
===Criterion===
The customary ("[[consequentialism|consequentialist]]") decision criterion of  cost-benefit analysis uses the summation of the effects  of the expected consequences of a decision on the well-being of people within its scope.  The alternative ("[[deontology|deontologist]]") decision criterion takes account of the views of those affected concerning the need to conform to predetermined rules (such as the sacredness of human life or the prohibition of interest-paying debt). To make a summation possible, a monetary cost or benefit is assigned to each of those effects. (Monetisation under the deontology criterion may be based upon the costs of socially-agreed practices that conform to the relevant rules)  The summation normally used is then that of the costs and benefits of  each effect, weighted by their estimated probability of occurrence, and discounted using the estimated time preference rates of those affected. The normal acceptance criterion for a single project is a positive  net present expected value of the excess of benefits over costs, and the normal  criterion for the acceptance of one among several alternatives  is that it should be the one with the  highest net present expected value.


==Methodology==
==Methodology==

Revision as of 03:50, 7 July 2010

This article is a stub and thus not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Addendum [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.

Cost-benefit analysis is used to evaluate projects that generate non-financial costs and benefits by taking account of the preferences of those affected. It has applications to the provision of public goods for which preferences are not reflected in market prices. Although its quantitative results are necessarily approximate, it can sometimes provide a persuasive guide to a choice among alternatives. It is claimed that, by taking account of the strengths of preferences, cost-benefit analysis can provide a better guide to choice than can be obtained from voting.

Introduction

The function of cost-benefit analysis is to inform a decision that is to be taken on behalf of others. The purpose of the information to be provided is to indicate whether the decision would be consistent with the preferences of those affected. The decision-maker's rôle is taken to be confined to the specification of its scope and of the decision-making criterion to be adopted. The analyst's functions are to forecast the material consequences of a decision, to evaluate each consequence in light of the preferences of those that would be affected, and to aggregate the resulting valuations. In response to the analysis the decision-maker may, however, adopt a precautionary interpretation of its findings in view of the risks involved.

Specification

Scope

The scope of an analysis is normally determined by the requirements of its prospective users. The evaluation of a medical procedure might, for example, be concerned solely with its effects on patients and their families, or it might also encompass effects on the hospital or on the public at large. An evaluation of migration commissioned by a European government might or might not be required to include effects upon migrants and their families, but an evaluation commissioned by the European Union might be expected to require the inclusion of effects upon all of its inhabitants. Some users require the coverage of a longer timescale than others, and environmental studies may even be required to encompass effects on future generations.

Criterion

The customary ("consequentialist") decision criterion of cost-benefit analysis uses the summation of the effects of the expected consequences of a decision on the well-being of people within its scope. The alternative ("deontologist") decision criterion takes account of the views of those affected concerning the need to conform to predetermined rules (such as the sacredness of human life or the prohibition of interest-paying debt). To make a summation possible, a monetary cost or benefit is assigned to each of those effects. (Monetisation under the deontology criterion may be based upon the costs of socially-agreed practices that conform to the relevant rules) The summation normally used is then that of the costs and benefits of each effect, weighted by their estimated probability of occurrence, and discounted using the estimated time preference rates of those affected. The normal acceptance criterion for a single project is a positive net present expected value of the excess of benefits over costs, and the normal criterion for the acceptance of one among several alternatives is that it should be the one with the highest net present expected value.

Methodology

Forecasting

Valuation

The outcomes whose valuations typically figure in cost-benefit analysis, include benefits such as the saving of time and the relief of suffering, and non-financial costs in the form of unwelcome experiences such as injury and exposure to noise. The monetary value to a person of such an outcome is taken to be the amount that he would be willing to pay in order to enjoy its benefits or avoid its costs. The preferred way of estimating that amount is the revealed preference method, which depends upon the observation of the subject's conduct in making free and well-informed choices. The collective valuation of an outcome can be reliably estimated from the price that is determined by choices made in an efficient market, a reasonable approximation to which is often provided by organised markets for products and services (and estimates of the value of time are often derived from the wage rates ruling in the labour market[1]). Relevant observations of the results of such choices are not always available, however, and other observed choices provide a less reliable basis for valuation. Estimates of the value of life derived from the payments or other benefits that are commonly accepted in return for conduct involving the risk of death, may be seriously distorted by probability blindness[2]. If the deontological criterion is considered appropriate, the value of life may alternatively be based upon the costs of community-determined practices concerning its preservation, such as prolonged hospitalisation.

In the absence of revealed preference methods, valuation may be based upon "stated preference" assessments involving surveys of those affected.

Aggregation

Interpretation

Applications

Health and safety

Transport

The environment

Climate change

Limitations

Metrics used in cost-benefit analyses

  • Cost per year of life saved[3] The definition of an acceptable cost per year of life saves ranges from $50,000 to $200,000.[4]
  • Cost of Preventing an Event (COPE)[5]. For example, to prevent a major vascular event n a high-risk adult , the number needed to treat is 19, the number of years of treatment are 5, and the daily cost of the generic drug is 68 cents. The COPE is 19 * 5 * ( 365 * .68) which equals $23,579 in the United States.
  • Years (or months or days) of life saved. "A gain in life expectancy of a month from a preventive intervention targeted at populations at average risk and a gain of a year from a preventive intervention targeted at populations at elevated risk can both be considered large."[6]
  • Quality-Adjusted Years of Life saved and Disability-Adjusted Years of Life saved. These are compound metrics that considers both the gain in duration life, adjusted by factors reflecting overall health and ability to function in those years. [7]

Standards in conducting a cost-benefit analysis

Standards have been developed for the conduct of cost-benefit analyses[8][8] and for systematic reviews of cost-benefit analyses[9].

The two most common problems in publications of cost-benefit analyses are not stating the study perspective (e.g. is the cost born by the patient, health case system, or society) and not disclosing the funding source.[10]

Difficulties in cost-benefit analyses

The costs saved by successful treatment of one disease may be offset by greater longevity leading to increased costs from other disease.[11]

Recommendations have bee published on how to read and interpret a cost-benefit analysis.[12][13][14][15]

[16]

[17]

References

  1. "The Value of Travel-Time", Oregon Department of Transportation, May 2004
  2. W. Kip Viscusi The Value of Life: Estimates with Risks by Occupation and Industry, Harvard Law School Discussion Paper No. 422, 2003
  3. Tengs TO et al (1995). "Five-hundred life-saving interventions and their cost-effectiveness". Risk Anal 15: 369–90. PMID 7604170[e]
  4. Cutler DM, Rosen AB, Vijan S (2006). "The value of medical spending in the United States, 1960-2000". N. Engl. J. Med. 355 (9): 920-7. DOI:10.1056/NEJMsa054744. PMID 16943404. Research Blogging.
  5. Maharaj R (2008). "Adding cost to NNT: the COPE statistic". ACP J. Club 148 (1): A8. PMID 18170986[e]
  6. Wright JC, Weinstein MC (1998). "Gains in life expectancy from medical interventions--standardizing data on outcomes". N Engl J Med 339: 380–6. PMID 9691106[e]
  7. Franco Sassi (2006), "Calculating QALYs, comparing QALY and DALY calculations", Health Policy and Planning 21 (5): 402-408, DOI:10.1093/heapol/czl018
  8. 8.0 8.1 Siegel JE, Weinstein MC, Russell LB, Gold MR (1996). "Recommendations for reporting cost-effectiveness analyses. Panel on Cost-Effectiveness in Health and Medicine". JAMA 276 (16): 1339–41. PMID 8861994[e] Cite error: Invalid <ref> tag; name "pmid8861994" defined multiple times with different content
  9. Jefferson T, Demicheli V, Vale L (2002). "Quality of systematic reviews of economic evaluations in health care". JAMA 287 (21): 2809-12. PMID 12038919[e]
  10. Neumann PJ, Stone PW, Chapman RH, Sandberg EA, Bell CM (2000). "The quality of reporting in published cost-utility analyses, 1976-1997". Ann. Intern. Med. 132 (12): 964-72. PMID 10858180[e]
  11. van Baal PH, Polder JJ, de Wit GA, et al (2008). "Lifetime Medical Costs of Obesity: Prevention No Cure for Increasing Health Expenditure". PLoS Med. 5 (2): e29. DOI:10.1371/journal.pmed.0050029. PMID 18254654. Research Blogging.
  12. Drummond MF, Richardson WS, O'Brien BJ, Levine M, Heyland D (1997). "Users' guides to the medical literature. XIII. How to use an article on economic analysis of clinical practice. A. Are the results of the study valid? Evidence-Based Medicine Working Group". JAMA 277 (19): 1552-7. PMID 9153371[e]
  13. O'Brien BJ, Heyland D, Richardson WS, Levine M, Drummond MF (1997). "Users' guides to the medical literature. XIII. How to use an article on economic analysis of clinical practice. B. What are the results and will they help me in caring for my patients? Evidence-Based Medicine Working Group". JAMA 277 (22): 1802-6. PMID 9178794[e]
  14. Greenhalgh T (1997). "How to read a paper. Papers that tell you what things cost (economic analyses)". BMJ 315 (7108): 596-9. PMID 9302961[e]
  15. Detsky AS, Naglie IG (1990). "A clinician's guide to cost-effectiveness analysis". Ann. Intern. Med. 113 (2): 147-54. PMID 2113784[e]
  16. Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government, HM Treasury, 2003
  17. Managing risks to the public: appraisal guidance, HM Treasury, 2005