Great Recession: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 9: Line 9:
The trigger that set it off was the malfunction of a part of  the  United States  housing market that  resulted in the downgrading by the [[credit rating  agency|credit rating agencies]] of large numbers of internationally-held [[asset (finance)|financial assets]] to create what came to be known as the [[subprime mortgage crisis]]. That crisis led to the discovery that  the [[banking#The 20th century|financial innovations]] that had been  richly rewarding traders in the financial markets,  had also  been threatening their collective survival. The  crucial nature of that threat  arose from the fact that the global economy had become  dependent upon the services of a well-functioning international financial system.  What was generally considered to be the impending collapse of the international financial system was averted towards the end of 2008 by widespread governmental guarantees of unlimited financial support to their countries' banks.
The trigger that set it off was the malfunction of a part of  the  United States  housing market that  resulted in the downgrading by the [[credit rating  agency|credit rating agencies]] of large numbers of internationally-held [[asset (finance)|financial assets]] to create what came to be known as the [[subprime mortgage crisis]]. That crisis led to the discovery that  the [[banking#The 20th century|financial innovations]] that had been  richly rewarding traders in the financial markets,  had also  been threatening their collective survival. The  crucial nature of that threat  arose from the fact that the global economy had become  dependent upon the services of a well-functioning international financial system.  What was generally considered to be the impending collapse of the international financial system was averted towards the end of 2008 by widespread governmental guarantees of unlimited financial support to their countries' banks.


The consensus view among economists  was that the combination of [[monetary policy|monetary]] and [[fiscal policy|fiscal]] expansion that was then undertaken by policy-makers was nevertheless  necessary to avoid  a global catastrophe, possibly  on the scale of the [[Great Depression]] of the 1930s - although there was  a body of opinion at the  time that considered a fiscal stimulus to be unnecessary, ineffective and potentially damaging<ref>[http://www.iea.org.uk/record.jsp?type=pressArticle&ID=376 ''Keynesian Over-spending Won't Rescue the Economy", Letter by IEA economists in the Sunday Telegraph, 26 October 2008]</ref>. Before those policy actions could take effect, there were  sharp reductions in  the levels of activity in most of the world's developed economies, mainly because of the discovery  by banks and households that they had been  overestimating the value of their assets. That discovery prompted  banks to reduce their lending, at first because of doubts about the reliability of the [[collateral (finance)|collateral]] offered by prospective borrowers and later, when those doubts receded, in order to avoid losing the confidence of their depositors by holding proportionately excessive amounts of debt. The practice  of  debt reduction (known as [[deleveraging]]) was also adopted by those households that had acquired historically high levels of indebtedness, many of whom were experiencing unaccustomed falls in the market value of their houses.
The consensus view among economists  was that the combination of [[monetary policy|monetary]] and [[fiscal policy|fiscal]] expansion that was then undertaken by policy-makers was nevertheless  necessary to avoid  a global catastrophe, possibly  on the scale of the [[Great Depression]] of the 1930s - although there was  a body of opinion at the  time that considered a fiscal stimulus to be unnecessary, ineffective and potentially damaging<ref>[http://www.iea.org.uk/record.jsp?type=pressArticle&ID=376 ''Keynesian Over-spending Won't Rescue the Economy", Letter by IEA economists in the Sunday Telegraph, 26 October 2008]</ref>. Before those policy actions could take effect, there were  sharp reductions in  the levels of activity in most of the world's developed economies, mainly because of the discovery  by banks and households that they had been  overestimating the value of their assets. That discovery prompted  banks to reduce their lending, at first because of doubts about the reliability of the [[collateral (finance)|collateral]] offered by prospective borrowers and later, when those doubts receded, in order to avoid losing the confidence of their depositors by holding proportionately excessive amounts of debt. The practice  of  debt reduction (known as [[deleveraging]]) was also adopted by those households that had acquired historically high levels of indebtedness, many of whom were experiencing unaccustomed falls in the market value of their houses. The effect of deleveraging by banks and by households was, in different ways,  to increase the severity of the developing [[recession]].


By the spring  of 2009, [[recession of 2009|the recession]] had involved most of the world's developed and developing economies. The countries  most affected  ''(as noted on the addendum subpage)'' were those with relatively large financial sectors (chiefly [[/Addendum#The United States| the United States]], [[/Addendum#The United Kingdom|the United Kingdom]],  [[/Addendum#Iceland|Iceland]] and [[/Addendum#Japan|Japan]]), those that were affected by the downturn in world trade because of their relatively large export sectors (including [[/Addendum#Germany|Germany]] and [[/Addendum#Japan|Japan]]) and those that experienced the bursting of house price [[bubble (economics)|bubbles]] (including [[/Addendum#The United States|The United States]],  [[/Addendum#The United Kingdom|The United Kingdom]], [[/Addendum#Ireland|Ireland]] and [[/Addendum#Spain|Spain]]), and although economic growth had returned to many economies by the end of 2009, unemployment continued rising and  [[output gap]] estimates  revealed the continuation of substantial underutilsation of productive capacity. Governments had been forced to borrow money by issuing [[bond]]s  to offset the fiscal consequences of their  [[automatic stabilisers]] and  their [[fiscal stimulus]]es, as a result of which there had beem substantial increases in [[national debt]]. In late 2009 and early 2010, the bond  markets  added several percentage points to the interest rates to be paid on the bond issues of several European governments to compensate for what was seen as a slight risk that they might  [[default (finance)|default]] on repayment, and in 2010 the economic policies of most developed countries came to be dominated by the problem of reducing national debt without hampering recovery.
By the spring  of 2009, [[recession of 2009|the recession]] had involved most of the world's developed and developing economies. The countries  most affected  ''(as noted on the addendum subpage)'' were those with relatively large financial sectors (chiefly [[/Addendum#The United States| the United States]], [[/Addendum#The United Kingdom|the United Kingdom]],  [[/Addendum#Iceland|Iceland]] and [[/Addendum#Japan|Japan]]), those that were affected by the downturn in world trade because of their relatively large export sectors (including [[/Addendum#Germany|Germany]] and [[/Addendum#Japan|Japan]]) and those that experienced the bursting of house price [[bubble (economics)|bubbles]] (including [[/Addendum#The United States|The United States]],  [[/Addendum#The United Kingdom|The United Kingdom]], [[/Addendum#Ireland|Ireland]] and [[/Addendum#Spain|Spain]]), and although economic growth had returned to many economies by the end of 2009, unemployment continued rising and  [[output gap]] estimates  revealed the continuation of substantial underutilsation of productive capacity. Governments had been forced to borrow money by issuing [[bond]]s  to offset the fiscal consequences of their  [[automatic stabilisers]] and  their [[fiscal stimulus]]es, as a result of which there had beem substantial increases in [[national debt]]. In late 2009 and early 2010, the bond  markets  added several percentage points to the interest rates to be paid on the bond issues of several European governments to compensate for what was seen as a slight risk that they might  [[default (finance)|default]] on repayment, and in 2010 the economic policies of most developed countries came to be dominated by the problem of reducing national debt without hampering recovery.

Revision as of 00:51, 15 March 2010

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Timelines [?]
Addendum [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Supplementary material

Links to news reports of the key events of the recession are available on the timelines subpage, accounts of the impact of the recession on individual countries are available on the addendum subpage, and definitions of the terms employed are available in the economics glossary and the finance glossary.

Overview

The Great Recession followed a twenty-year period that has been termed the "Great Moderation", during which recessions had been less frequent and less severe than in previous periods, and during which there been a great deal of successful financial innovation. Attitudes and habits of thought acquired during that period were to have a significant influence upon what was to come. Among other significant influences were the globalisation of financial markets, with the development of large international capital flows, often from the developing to the developed economies; the large-scale granting of credit to households in some of the major economies; and the creation there of house price booms, that have since been categorised as bubbles, but were not recognised as such at the time. It struck the major economies at a time when they were suffering from the impact of a supply shock in which a surge in commodity prices was causing households to reduce their spending, and as a result of which economic forecasters were expecting a mild downturn.

The trigger that set it off was the malfunction of a part of the United States housing market that resulted in the downgrading by the credit rating agencies of large numbers of internationally-held financial assets to create what came to be known as the subprime mortgage crisis. That crisis led to the discovery that the financial innovations that had been richly rewarding traders in the financial markets, had also been threatening their collective survival. The crucial nature of that threat arose from the fact that the global economy had become dependent upon the services of a well-functioning international financial system. What was generally considered to be the impending collapse of the international financial system was averted towards the end of 2008 by widespread governmental guarantees of unlimited financial support to their countries' banks.

The consensus view among economists was that the combination of monetary and fiscal expansion that was then undertaken by policy-makers was nevertheless necessary to avoid a global catastrophe, possibly on the scale of the Great Depression of the 1930s - although there was a body of opinion at the time that considered a fiscal stimulus to be unnecessary, ineffective and potentially damaging[1]. Before those policy actions could take effect, there were sharp reductions in the levels of activity in most of the world's developed economies, mainly because of the discovery by banks and households that they had been overestimating the value of their assets. That discovery prompted banks to reduce their lending, at first because of doubts about the reliability of the collateral offered by prospective borrowers and later, when those doubts receded, in order to avoid losing the confidence of their depositors by holding proportionately excessive amounts of debt. The practice of debt reduction (known as deleveraging) was also adopted by those households that had acquired historically high levels of indebtedness, many of whom were experiencing unaccustomed falls in the market value of their houses. The effect of deleveraging by banks and by households was, in different ways, to increase the severity of the developing recession.

By the spring of 2009, the recession had involved most of the world's developed and developing economies. The countries most affected (as noted on the addendum subpage) were those with relatively large financial sectors (chiefly the United States, the United Kingdom, Iceland and Japan), those that were affected by the downturn in world trade because of their relatively large export sectors (including Germany and Japan) and those that experienced the bursting of house price bubbles (including The United States, The United Kingdom, Ireland and Spain), and although economic growth had returned to many economies by the end of 2009, unemployment continued rising and output gap estimates revealed the continuation of substantial underutilsation of productive capacity. Governments had been forced to borrow money by issuing bonds to offset the fiscal consequences of their automatic stabilisers and their fiscal stimuluses, as a result of which there had beem substantial increases in national debt. In late 2009 and early 2010, the bond markets added several percentage points to the interest rates to be paid on the bond issues of several European governments to compensate for what was seen as a slight risk that they might default on repayment, and in 2010 the economic policies of most developed countries came to be dominated by the problem of reducing national debt without hampering recovery.

Background: the great moderation

The economy

[2]

The financial system

Household debt

The housing market

Downturn and recovery

Commmodity prices

The subprime mortgage crisis

The crash of 2008

The recession of 2009

Recovery and aftermath

Diagnosis,treatments and remedies

References