Dividend Discount Model: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Subpagination Bot
m (Add {{subpages}} and remove any categories (details))
imported>Aleta Curry
(clean up opening, don't have specialist knowledge to continue)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{subpages}}
{{subpages}}


The '''Dividend Discount Model''' (DDM) is a widely used approach to value common stocks. Financial theory states that the value of any securities is worth the present value of all future cash flow the owner will receive. If we assume that stock investor receive all their cash fow in the form of dividend, a DDM will give the intrinsic value for a stock.  
The '''Dividend Discount Model''' ('''DDM''') is a widely used approach to value common [[stock]]s. In financial theory, the value of any securities is worth the present value of all future cash flow the owner will receive. If we assume that stock investors receive all their cash flow in the form of [[dividend]], a DDM will give the intrinsic value for a stock.  


A [[common stock]] can be tough as the right to receive future [[dividend]]s. A stock's intrinsic value can be defined as the value of all future dividends discounted at the appropriate discount rate. In its simpliest form, the DDM uses, as [[discount rate]], the investor's required rate of return.
A [[common stock]] can be thought of as the right to receive future dividends. A stock's intrinsic value can be defined as the value of all future dividends discounted at the appropriate discount rate. In its simplest form, the DDM uses, as [[discount rate]], the investor's required rate of return.


Mathematically, it can be expressed as:
The DDM can be expressed mathematically as:
<math>V_0=\sum_{t=1}^{\infty} \frac{D_t}{(1+k)^n}</math>,
<math>V_0=\sum_{t=1}^{\infty} \frac{D_t}{(1+k)^n}</math>,


where <math>D_t</math> is the expected dividend in period <math>t</math> and <math>k</math> is the required rate of return for the investor.
where <math>D_t</math> is the expected dividend in period <math>t</math> and <math>k</math> is the required rate of return for the investor.


Historically, this formula is a special form of the discounted cash flow model proposed by the seminal book by [[John Burr Williams|John B. Williams]], ''The Theory of Investment Value'' published in 1938.
Historically, this formula is a special form of the discounted cash flow model proposed by [[John Burr Williams|John B. Williams]] in his seminal book ''The Theory of Investment Value'', published in 1938.


From this formula, one can deduct that the most important components of the value of a stock are likely to be the size and the timing of the expected dividend. The larger it is, and the more quick the shareholder receive it, the higher the share value will be.  
From this formula, one can deduct that the most important components of the value of a stock are likely to be the size and the timing of the expected dividend. The larger it is (?) <!--which
'it'? should it be "these are"?-->, and the quicker the shareholders receive it (?) <!--them-->, the higher the share value will be.  


==Assumptions of the model==
==Assumptions of the model==

Revision as of 00:59, 13 April 2008

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

The Dividend Discount Model (DDM) is a widely used approach to value common stocks. In financial theory, the value of any securities is worth the present value of all future cash flow the owner will receive. If we assume that stock investors receive all their cash flow in the form of dividend, a DDM will give the intrinsic value for a stock.

A common stock can be thought of as the right to receive future dividends. A stock's intrinsic value can be defined as the value of all future dividends discounted at the appropriate discount rate. In its simplest form, the DDM uses, as discount rate, the investor's required rate of return.

The DDM can be expressed mathematically as: ,

where is the expected dividend in period and is the required rate of return for the investor.

Historically, this formula is a special form of the discounted cash flow model proposed by John B. Williams in his seminal book The Theory of Investment Value, published in 1938.

From this formula, one can deduct that the most important components of the value of a stock are likely to be the size and the timing of the expected dividend. The larger it is (?) , and the quicker the shareholders receive it (?) , the higher the share value will be.

Assumptions of the model

  • The future value of dividend is know by the investor.
  • Dividends are expected to be distributed at the end of each year until infinity.
  • Dividends are the only way investors get money back from the company. This implies that any share buyback would be ignored.
  • The implication of the second assumption is that the investor is expected to hold the share for an infinite period: he will not sell it, an any moment.

While the model may be of some (perhaps significant) theoretical value, these assumptions, at the same time, indicate the limitations of this model. In reality, dividends can vary considerably. Also, few investors have an indefinite holding period of a particular stock. In general, investors tend to sell a particular stock after a certain period, for a variety of reasons. These limitations mean that the practical value of the Dividend Discount Model is limited.

Inputs to the model

To estimate the value of a common share, one must know at least:

  • : the expected dividend to be received in one year;
  • : the required rate of return on the investment. There are many methods to estimate this required rate of return, the most common is the Nobel-prize rewarded Capital Asset Pricing Model;
  • : the expected growth rate in dividends.

Zero Growth dividend

In the case where the dividend is not expected to growth in the future (), then the stock is also known as a perpetuity.

In that case, the price of the stock would be equal to:

,

where is the expected constant dividend and is the required rate of return for the investor.

Constant Growth dividend

In the case where the dividend is expected to grow at a definite constant growth rate , the value of the stock will be equal to

,

where is the expected constant dividend at period (), is the dividend growth rate and is the required rate of return for the investor.

It is also known as the Gordon Model for evaluating stocks.

Supernormal growth model

In many cases, companies do not growth at a constant rate during their life. They are expected to growth at a "supernormal" growth rate at the beginning of their activities and then, at maturity, the growth rate will be reduce to a constant "normal" growth rate. This model is also know as the Two-Stage Dividend Discount Model.

In that case, we will have to adjust the calculation to take in account those two different growth periods.

If we assume that a company will have its dividend growing at a rate during the first periods and thereafter, until infinity, at a lower rate , the value of the company will be equal to:


Where is the dividend distributed today, and is the required rate of return or the investor.

This method is usually used by analysts in valuing companies as the short-term growth is, in most cases, higher than the long-term growth (generally set at the general economic growth rate).

References

  • Damodaran A. (2002) , Investment Valuation, Tools and Techniques for Determining the Value of Any Asset, 2nd Edition, Wiley.
  • Ross S., Westerfield R., Jaffe J.(2005) Corporate Finance, 6th Edition, Mc-Graw Hill
  • Williams, John B. (1938), The Theory of Investment Value, Cambridge, MA., Harvard University Press

See Also

Gordon Model